WHAT IS NECESSARY TO PROMOTE THE DEVELOPMENT OF BIOGAS IN POLAND
WHAT IS NECESSARY TO PROMOTE THE DEVELOPMENT OF BIOGAS IN POLAND
Randy Mott, VP Polish Biogas
Association
The new
government in Poland has been expressing an interest in increasing the
development of biogas in Poland. This is encouraging for a variety of reasons
since biogas has very significant benefits beyond simply producing electricity.
These include generation of a nearly equivalent amount of heat, replacement of
aging small coal-fired heating plants, increasing the nutrient uptake of
organic material used as fertilizer, reducing run-off of substances that cause
eutrophication of local water bodies, and reducing the cost of organic waste
disposal for local residents and businesses. Biogas also operates constantly at the same
level of output and that output can even by varied to match the demand curve if
there is some compensation for the extra effort to do so.
PBA has
documented that the cost-effectiveness of biogas is among the highest in the
mix of renewable energy technologies because it provides these collateral
benefits. For compliance with the mandatory EU RES target for 2020, biogas
produces both renewable electricity and heat that both count toward the goal
and at an aggregate price that is still comparable to other electricity-only
technologies.
How does Poland
then get these benefits without creating the very high subsidies[1]
that were used in Germany to develop the biogas sector in that country? Besides
setting the support level at the appropriate level, based on real economic
data, and changing the procedure used to provide support from the small auction
set out in the new law to a more stable and predictable one (both discussed
below), there are also several simple measures that can be taken that actually
do not increase the cost burden on either tax-payers or energy end-users, but actually
reduce their cost.
Cost of Biogas
The European
Commission has estimated that about 70% of the Member States do not provide
sufficient support to make biogas viable in those countries.[2]
It is essential that support for biogas
be based on smart policies since simply throwing a lot of money at the problem
will be happen. The cost for biogas plants varies based on whether the methane
recovered comes from waste-water treatment, landfills or specially constructed
anaerobic digestion plants. The anaerobic digestion plants can be simple
farm-based designs or more expensive plants designed to treat organic waste
materials. Variations in cost include design elements to control odors (such as
special waste reception halls, steel digesters with welded covers, odor control
via biological and/or chemical filters) as well substrate or feedstock
pretreatment via high temperature. The average cost of anaerobic digestion
plants (which is the main topic of interest in Poland) has been relatively
steady over the years. In 2010, the European Biogas Association set out the
cost of electricity production by size of plant and those numbers are still fairly
accurate:
The Fraunhofer
Institute in Germany reported that the cost of biogas in Germany in 2013
ranged from 14 to 21 Euro cents per kWhr (no breakdown by plant size).[3]
Unlike other renewable energy
technologies, biogas costs are not going down: “no reduction in the specific investment
costs in recent years can be identified. “ Fraunhofer, supra. The
critical factors in the cost of biogas are plant size, heat utilization and
substrate costs. Substrate costs include
not only acquisition in most cases, but can include pretreatment, storage,
dewatering, etc. The proposed Polish auction reference price for less
than 1 MW is 500 PLN/MWhr. This is only 11 Euro cents compared to the
cost cited above. Adding co-generation support where heat is utilized outside
the biogas plant needs can add about 2-3 Euro cents per MWhr of electricity
produced (based on the assumption of 120 PLN/MWhr for co-gen support).[4]
These numbers are still too low to provide adequate support for biogas
projects without the use of a sizable grant for the capital costs. Grant
funding is limited and has been the basis for the overwhelming number of
current agricultural biogas plants in Poland. This is a major reason why the
number is so low. The IEO numbers should
be the assumed level of necessary support. See
CITE.
Policy Changes for
Biogas
Making the
support system for biogas attractive enough to obtain equity and debt financing
requires some revisions. First, it is obvious that larger plants are more
economic feasible and can provide a value to the public. The current arbitrary
size of 1 MW for exclusion for the large auction should be raised to 2 MW. Most
existing agricultural biogas plants in Poland and most in development in 2014
were over 1 MW. This reflects the economic and technical reality on the
ground and should be acknowledged in the support scheme.
Second, auctions
are unattractive for small projects like biogas plants. No successful
auction for biogas plants to produce electricity has been held anywhere in the
world.[5]
Small and medium-sized enterprises that do this projects are quite reluctant to
initiate the front-end costs with no assurance that they will obtain support
for the project in the end and no knowledge of what the level of support will
be until just months before the auction (while their front-end expenditures
must start 24-36 months before the qualification to bid can be established).
Plants that are proceeding in Poland are virtually only those with grants that
must be used in the short-term. Biogas projects without grants getting prepared
for a future and uncertain auction are almost non-existent.
We expect that the European Commission will
find the small auction inconsistent with the GBER regulation in that it is not
“competitive” under the Commission’s rules. It is also clear that under the
general state aid rules the small auction distorts competition by limiting
small projects and disproportionately hurts small and medium-size enterprises.
This will also adversely affect the technology mix in Poland by continue to
push onshore wind and biomass co-firing at the expense of other technologies. Some other mechanism is necessary whether it
be a fixed feed-in tariff or continuation of green certificates at the option
of the developer.
Agricultural
biogas plants under the current law are restricted to certain substrates, which
are narrower in scope than those that are covered by the full EU definition.
Poland may wish for farm-based plants to not treat sewage sludge, for example,
or household food waste (since these materials require special handling and
processing). But the “other biogas” category
in the new law should allow for their use as feedstock. PBA has argued for the
Danish rule that allows 20% by weight of sewage sludge to be handling in an AD
plant.[6]
This would be a high temperature or thermophilic plant and our experts suggest
70 degrees pretreating for a hour of the material as well.[7] Allowing sewage sludge in a limited portion
as well as household food wastes would increase the prospects of biogas
development in Poland. Anaerobic digestion is also the best environmental and
public health management option for these materials. This effort would also have to provide that
the support for such plants would not be lowering that for “agricultural biogas
plants” under the law. While some gate fees might be possible for the
processing of sewage sludge and household food wastes, the market has not been
established at this point in Poland to expect these fees to cover the extra
cost of handling this material. PBA
suggest that “other biogas” AD plants receive the same level of support as “agricultural”
plants until the market demonstrates, if ever, that a lower level of support is
feasible.
The immediate
effect of a broader substrate policy would be to reduce the cost to local
government and residents for sewage sludge and household food waste disposal.
The alternative for smaller towns and rural areas is composting of this
material under the current law and that is only a cost to residents with no
off-setting revenue. This rule would
also enable larger 1-2 MW biogas plants in Poland to deal with the increasingly
strict EU rules on organic waste management (including the new Circular Economy
Directive). The full scope of substrates within EU definitions should be
allowed in “other biogas” plants to assure the optimum development of this sector
in Poland.
PBA has also
urged the Polish Government to adopt the rule that up to 2% of the feedstock
can be additives such as glycerin and enzymes. These are often necessary to
assure stable energy output and hence financially feasibility of the plant.
Enzymes hold the promise of revolutionizing biogas in the future and should not
be precluded from use in Poland. The European Commission Joint Research Center
recommended this rule in its review of the technical issues in the biowaste
“End of Waste” studies.
Support by
size of plant should be re-introduced. As the EBA data illustrate, there is
a wide disparity in the cost of electricity production by plant size. Forcing
the smallest plants to compete in an auction against 1 MW plants makes it very
difficult for them to receive support. The only thing providing any prospect of
support in the current law is the fact that there will be more support set
aside in the small auction than there will be bids. But this violates the EU
competition rules as well as provides no assurance that any smaller plants can
be economically feasible.
We are thus lead to the inevitable point
that auctions cannot be used effectively or legally for this type of renewable
energy. Poland needs graduated system
of support for biogas similar to that recommended in 2013 by the Institute
for Renewable Energy in their report for the Ministry of Economy. “Analiza DotyczÄ…ca MożliwoÅ›ci
Określenia Niezbędnej Wysokości Wsparcia Dla Poszczególnych Technologii Oze W Kontekście Realizacji
„Krajowego Planu DziaÅ‚ania W Zakresie Energii Ze ŹródeÅ‚ Odnawialnych,” Lipiec
2013. This can be provided by feed-in tariffs fixed for the same period
as now proposed in the law on auctions.
Making the Transition
Effective
However, there is
a much more complex issue at work here. It is already 2016 and Poland needs to
make a genuine effort to meet the 2020 deadline from the EU for RES. Any
mechanism for new support for RES must realistically provide a means to assure
a continuous development and commissioning of new RES sources over the next
four years. We do not have this situation at this point.
The European
Commission is reviewing the Green Certificate law and will require that it be
modified to meet the state aid rules in effect from 2005-2017. That means the
end of some support (old hydro) and the downward adjustment of other support
(co-firing biomass with coal). It also means adjustment of biogas
certificates to reflect the actual costs of production.[8]
These points were clearly made to the former government by the head of the
Office of Competition and Consumer Protection[9]
but they were ignored. This process will
require an emergency legislative act that probably can use a mark-up of the
previous 2013 draft law that providing for this approach.
Once this effort
is done, which will have to be in 2016, we suggest that the new certificate
system be extended to allow the orderly transition to whatever new system
is to be used. For large sources, this would be an auction and for small ones
(under 2 MW) it would be a fixed payment reflecting a “contract for the
difference.” PBA strongly suggests that
it is necessary and appropriate to allow new projects to continue to opt for
support under the revised certificate system if they elect not to participate
in the new system. Continuing this approach until 2018 or even 2020 may be
essential to achieve the EU-mandated 2020 target.[10] This proposal also has the advantage of
working off of a system that has been in place for many years and no new
mechanisms need to be established. Rules of certificate coefficients have to be
developed in any event due to the EU state aid matter. Once this is done, it establishes a method to
simply keep the system going in the transition to something else.
Conclusion
Assuring a
technology mix that capitalizes on Poland’s national resources must include a
major biogas element. Biogas meets the 2020 objectives in a cost-effective
manner by producing both electricity and heat that count toward the target. It
also has several other benefits to farmers, consumers, and local
governments.
To achieve these
benefits, Poland needs to make sure the system of support is based on the real
economics of biogas. Rules that assure
small farm-based plants are allowed to obtain fair support are critical and now
absent. A system that allows the optimum
–sized biogas plants (1-2MW) is also lacking. Forcing competition in a general
auction for projects above 1 MW based solely on electricity prices means no
biogas can be developed over 1 MW at this point. Restricting substrates and/or support to not
use the full scope of material allowed by the EU definitions is also without
any sense. These biogas policy changes
are relatively simple and their rationale is quite clear.
The bigger and
more complex picture is how to meet the 2020 target, satisfy the European
Commission state aid rules, assure Poland’s own energy potential is used in an
optimum manner, and provide a level of support sufficient to induce investment
but not so excessive as to significantly and adversely affect energy prices.[11] Our proposal for this problem is to use the
adjusted certificate program based on costs of production, as approved by the
EC, in the interim as new measures are implemented. The revised certificate program must be done
promptly to meet EC rules in any event, but it also provides a means to
continue the construction of new projects in the next several years. Shifting
entirely to the auctions will kill the small projects and delay the larger ones
so that the 2020 target cannot be reached by any measures. The
revised certificate system can also be used to satisfy the newest state aid
rules.
PBA is happy to cooperate in any way to
promote the discussion of these issues and their careful and transparent
evaluation by the Government and the public.
[1] Germany provided from 19 to 29 Euro cents a
kWhr for biogas from 2008. See Spath,
THE SUCCESS FACTORS OF THE
DEVELOPMENT OF BIOGAS WITHIN GERMANY - A CASE STUDY, thesis, 2013. Even
with these high levels of support, many German biogas plants had financial
trouble over the years. Before the 2008 changes, about half of the German
plants were insolvent. Michael Kottner, Director of the German Biogas
Institute, speech September 10, 2008,
Sofia, Bulgaria. Poland now proposes just 11 Euro cents kWhr in the
reference price.
[2] European Commission, “The support of electricity from renewable energy sources,”
COM(2005) 627 final
{SEC(2005) 1571}, p. 8.
[3]
Fraunhofer Institute, Levelized Cost Of Electricity Renewable
Energy Technologies: Study,
November 2013. Support in 2012 in Germany was reduced to about 17 Euro cents
per kWhr on average.
[4]
There is a move to make co-generation support also awarded by auctions. This
would likely spell the end to any new biogas projects, if the developer has to
assume that he can successfully win support in two different auctions over a
period of time before construction can commence (after incurring all of the
front-end costs of the project).
[5] The Instituto de Investigación Tecnológica in
Spain published a detailed review of renewable energy
auction experience in every country where it has been attempted. See del
Rio and Linares, “Back to the future? Rethinking Auctions for Renewable Electricity
Support,” 2013. One of their major points from
looking at dozens of different auction systems was as follows: “Unfortunately, these theoretical advantages of
auctions come at a cost. Due to the complexity of the bureaucratic procedures,
and also to the planning required ahead, auctions have higher transaction costs
(Finon and Menanteau 2008) which, together with uncertainties on the final
price and the tendering schedule, deter participation by smaller firms,
resulting in a low degree of competition (Butler and Neuhoff, 2008), and creating
opportunities for market power. In turn, this may eliminate the higher
theoretical efficiency of this instrument”. Id. at p. 3. Later in their paper after reviewing every
country’s auction experiences, they conclude: “Unfriendly for small projects and actors. A major empirical lesson of tenders is that they are
unsuitable for small installations and smaller actors. Competition may thus
be affected. It has been argued that some of the aforementioned factors and,
namely, information failure and difficult access to finance, have a disproportionately
negative impact on small actors and, thus, that the instrument is not
suitable for small actors, suggesting that smaller projects should be
promoted with a different instrument (Morthorst et al 2005, Mitchell 1995).
… In contrast, smaller projects may need to be promoted with another
instrument.[emphasis added]. Their conclusion is based on the empirical
data, not simply another expert opinion. Auctions may achieve some support “optimization”
for large projects, but they kill smaller projects. In fact, most auction
regimes exempt up to 5 MW projects or even larger. The adverse competitive
impact of auctions is especially true of biogas: the ITT study noted that many
countries had no biogas projects successfully bid in their auctions.
[6] See CEERES White Paper on Sewage Sludge; PBA Sporadyczne użycie osadu ściekowego nie
powinno redukować wsparcia w zapisach ustawy o OZE, 22 września 2014; Instytut Uprawy Nawożenia i Gleboznawstwa
Państwowy Instytut Badawczy, Możliwości Rolniczego wykorzystania pozostałości
po fermentacji metanowej zmieszanych odpadów z udziałem osadów ściekowych,
Puławy 2012.
[7] See IUNG, note 6.
[8] “As
stated in point 59, 1st subparagraph, of the environmental guidelines, Member
States may compensate for the difference between the production cost of
renewable energy and the market price of the form of power concerned.
Thus, such compensation can relate only to the extra production
costs for environmentally friendly electricity production as compared to the
production costs for energy based on conventional energy sources.” cited
in Commission Decision of 24 April 2007 on the State aid scheme implemented by
Slovenia in the framework of its legislation on qualified energy
producers — Case No C 7/2005, para. 85. In the case of
certificate systems, the Commission has been consistent in requiring
proportionality to actual or reasonably expected costs of production across
different technologies. See C(2010)2211, State aid No N 65/2010 -
United Kingdom Amendments to the Renewables Obligation Certificates (ROCs)
scheme, March 30, 2010 (“…levelised costs matching the midpoint
of the predicted revenues… will therefore prevent overcompensation in the
aggregate of the different producers”). Romania used a levelized cost
calculation to evenly apply the green certificates for different technologies,
based upon production costs for each technology. C (2011) 4938, State aid SA.
33134 2011/N– RO, Green certificates for promoting electricity from renewable
sources, July 13, 2011 p. 8-9.
[9] The head of the Office of Competition and
Consumer Protection (UOKiK) communicated this to the Ministry of Economy on November
28, 2013:. According to the OCCP, the certificate
system constitutes state aid. “Detailed clarification in regard
has been presented in previous correspondence [citing June 5, 2012 and August
10, 2012 correspondence from UKOK to MG]'. Moreover, similar
conclusions have been expressed by the European Commission within the framework
of the ongoing process notification of the restoration of the certificate
system for high-efficiency co-generation.” [referring to
the Commission's May 31, 2013 opinion on co-generation certificates
in Poland, S.A. 36518](emphasis added). The DG Competition that handles the
state aid issue in Brussels communicated to UOKiK formally on May 31, 2013
requesting the detailed information to determine if there was market
distortion or overcompensation. This is especially relevant to the Green
Certificate action by the Commission also still pending, since it asked for
information about "levelized cost of production. “The compatibility of the
aid with the competition rules only arises with the DG Competition if there is
actually state aid. From this formal communication and the UOKiK letter to the
Ministry is seems clear that there was also likely oral communication with the
Commission on the issue as well. and possibly other less formal correspondence.
At any rate, UOKiK concluded that the Commission believed the
certificates (both co-generation and Green) were state aid. [This
should be no surprise, since a nearly identical Romanian system of
Green Certificates was determined to be state aid in 2011). The new law in
Poland actually assumes that Green Certificates are state aid in calculating
the permitted intensity of aid for each project. Article 39.2, RES Act of April
2015. See blog
post.
[10] The obligation of electricity providers to
have a mandatory percent of renewable electricity in their mix is still the law
and the use of certificates will be essential for them to meet this obligation.
The elimination of old hydro certificates (from 2005 to date) and the reduction
of co-firing support by half for the same period will cut the certificate
availability and market dramatically. Large projects under the auction will not
be built until 2018 or later. Most auctioned energy will not be in place by
2020 and cannot be used for compliance with the 2020 target or to reduce the
electricity providers’ RES quota obligation. New sources of certificates will
be essential to the orderly functioning of the energy system in Poland.
[11]
Studies have shown that the auction mechanism does not generally produce a
stable amount of projects at the predicted prices. While low bids may be
common, these quite often lead to projects that cannot be built. There is very
little confidence that what is auctioned will actually be built and when this
will occur. Penalties can never be large enough to compel construction of
projects that will lose money over their entire life of operation. High
qualification standards and penalties combined with low reference prices often
also lead to little or no bids being received.
Comments