This paper was originally published in 2015 in the European Energy Journal and presented at the PowerrGen2015 conference in Rotterdam. It was incorporated into the position papers of the Green Party in the EU Parliament. The conclusions have been borne out over time with EU renewable energy investment declining due to increased market barriers (data up to 2020). See AURES II, "How (not) to respond
to low competition in
renewable energy
auctions
Endogenous rationing in renewable energy auctions," Policy Brief June 2020 (funded by EU Horizon 2020).
The European Community grew out of a generation-old dream to create a single market across numerous European countries. Explicit in this concept was the realization from the beginning that the various national governments in this community should be restrained from providing the traditional government assistance to their own businesses, which by its very nature weakened competition and created uneven playing fields across national boundaries in the community.
The Treaty for the Functioning of the European Union in Articles 107 and 108 create a special role for the European Commission to review state aid to assure that such distortions of competition are minimized. State aid to promote renewable energy has been routinely reviewed by the Commission and since 2008 guidelines have been used to determine its compatibility with the treaty. This article describes how the latest changes to the guidelines have already lead to lower renewable energy investment and how they will likely be frustrated in their intent to provide more cost-effective support.
The European Commission revised state aid guidelines in 2014 (
Guidelines on State aid for environmental protection and energy 2014-2020, 2014/C 200/01) mark a major departure from the policies used since 2008. Effective in 2017, they will generally require “competitive market mechanisms” for state aid to renewable energy. The objective of the Commission’s new guidelines is to attempt to focus entirely on cost-effectiveness of support. “The selection process should lead to the selection of beneficiaries that can address the environmental or energy objectives using the least amount of aid or in the most cost-effective way.” Id. at par. 99. In their opinion, this can be in the form of auctions for feed-in premiums or technology-neutral certificates. The biggest change is their reversal of the presumption that support should be levelized by each technology’s production cost. The Commission now assumes that technologies can be supported by a technology-neutral system, subject to some exceptions. But by combining this presumption of uniform support instruments with the new block grant exemption rules (which exempt technology-neutral auctions from notification), the Commission is pushing its policy on Member States previously allowed by the RES Directive to have wide latitude in implementing their support schemes.
The changes come on the heels of major pressure from conventional energy utilities in several Member States. See EuroElectric, “Renewable Energy And Security Of Supply: Finding Market Solutions,” October 2014. Unfortunately, the European body charged with enforcing unfair and anticompetitive practices has failed to scrutinize complaints from the large European utilities about RES support. The portions of the new Guidelines for State Aid for Environmental Protection that deal with renewable energy seem ideally suited to promote energy market share for the bigger players, while doing a “hatchet job” on distributed energy. Once fully implemented by 2017, these new rules may have little effect on lowering the cost of renewable energy, but they will shape the renewable energy sector is ways that will undermine competition and hurt consumers.
The rationale
Push back on renewable energy has come from two directions: (1) increases in electricity prices in some countries due to over-compensation of renewable energy producers; (2) changes in the role of traditional electricity producers in the supplying base-load due to the preference for renewables. These arguments have been adopted pretty much in their entirely by the DG Competition in the new state aid guidelines. Unfortunately, their solutions to these demands will not help resolve the claimed problems and in some ways will aggravate the problems.
It is quite ironic that the Commission found that over-compensation of renewable energy was a problem in its explanation of the new guidelines, since virtually every RES system of support has been reviewed for potential over-compensation and each was approved by the Commission.
If over-compensation was problem, each support system approved by the Commission was found to have means to adjust the support. Many Member States have done so, albeit often in erratic ways that have caused market distortion in themselves. There is really no basis for now claiming that feed-in tariffs or certificate systems must inherently result in over-compensation and therefore need to be replaced with auctions.
Ultimately, the Commission was on the right track under the old rules, still effective until 2017, requiring a levelized support system that did not theoretically over-compensate some technologies beyond a reasonable profit margin. If anything, the Commission has lacked the political will to single out over-compensation or under-compensation. Member States are free under the RES Directive to select their own means of reaching the 2020 targets. They submit National Renewable Energy Action Plans to achieve the numbers by specific assumptions about the technologies that will be developed. This critical point is ignored by the DG Commission in looking at support systems. While every Member State did not provide an adequate margin of profit in its support system for biogas [70% fail to do so], for instance, the technologies specified in the National Action Plan should be compensated consistent with their actual costs of production, including means to adjust this for new facilities as those costs may change over time. For about fourteen years, the DG Commission has followed this approach of levelization, but has never applied it strictly to the technologies enumerated in the national plans.
The other leg of the case for reform is the argument that renewable energy is distorting the market to the detriment of conventional energy producers. By pre-empting the base load, renewables have cut into the utilization rates of coal-fired and gas-fired plants. The state aid guidelines do not directly address this issue. Since the mandate for renewable energy from the European Parliament requires widespread deployment of renewable energy in any event, the role of marginally competitive traditional energy will be challenged under any system. In fact, competition from renewable energy has created some downward pressure on end-users prices that actually mitigates much of the cost of the support system. So critics argue at the same time that RES is too expensive and that it is too cheap.
In fact, the need for balancing to adjust for the variations in some renewable energy outputs can be accomplished under any system and nothing about the Commission’s auction plans is necessary to address this issue. See EcoFys, “Design features of support schemes for renewable electricity,” January 2014 [a wide ranging discussion of the issues under all forms of support]. However, the Commission’s solution in the new guidelines makes some feasible balancing practices more difficult, not easier.
Competitive Procedures?
The theory embraced by the Commission is that competitive procedures allow the Member State to specify how much renewable energy they want at a given time and what the maximum price will be.
This can extend to “banded” technology specific auctions as well as “free-for-alls” of competing technologies. The setting of the reference price, the pre-qualifications and potential penalties for failure to deliver on a winning bid are critical to the outcome. Without sufficient prequalification requirements (such as building permits, environmental and planning approvals, etc.) as well as penalties for failure to construct facilities that win the auction, most projects historically do not get built at all. Low bidders gamble on winning while figuring out if they can proceed after the auction. On the other hand, extensive prequalification requirements (the ones listed here can require 24-36 months of preparation) and substantial penalties for non-performance can lead to insufficient bidders to create any competition or to no bidders at all.
As we will discuss below, most auctions in the RES sector have resulted in one or the other undesirable outcomes. A small minority have actually worked according to the theory. EcoFys in their report for the Commission in January 2014 reached a conclusion at odds with the Commission’s ultimate guidelines: “
At present, RES-support with auctions is still undergoing a learning phase…” Supra, page 73 (emphasis added). Even auction advocates concede that “[d]ue to negative past experiences with a third instrument (auctions), this instrument has been broadly dismissed in academics….” Del Rio et al, “Back to the Future,”
Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 35 (2014).
Although the overwhelming majority of attempted RES auctions have had major problems to date, the Commission is pushing to expand the experiment to the whole EU-28.
The basic problem described above, i.e. “threading the needle” between lowering the burden of bidding to encourage competition in bids and more restrictive pre-qualifications so that winning projects are actually built, has seldom been done successfully. In a report prepared for the European Commission, EcoFys et al noted in January 2014: “…finding a compromise between encouraging high implementation rates without reducing the number of market participants too much proved to be a difficult task.” Design features of support schemes for renewable electricity, January 2014, p. 5.
One irony is that auctions have not necessarily lower costs. Some auctions have resulted in no major savings, since bidders must add the risk factor to their financial projection.
“Compared to feed-in systems, the auction introduces additional elements of uncertainty for project developers regarding revenues and the future realization of committed projects. This in turn makes planning more difficult and can in some cases lead to higher risk premiums.” EcoFys, supra, page 45.
Thus, Germany actually recently had comparable or lower support for PV than the French achieved in their auctions.
“The price of PV in French auctions (red line) fell from around 23 cents per kilowatt-hour to around 17 cents during 2012-13, whereas German feed-in tariffs (orange line) brought prices down from just under 25 cents to below 14 cents during the same timeframe.” Morris, “
Actual outcomes of auctions in France, Brazil, and the Netherlands,” June 15, 2014. There is substantial doubt that an auction by using maximum bid prices or reference prices can hit the right market price any better than other support mechanisms. In Brazil, a PV auction ended with no bids: “It should also be pointed out that the round of bidding in the fall of 2013 did not elicit a single submission for photovoltaics because the starting price was far too low.”
Auctions have also notoriously failed to assure that projects actually get built.
Firms bid the project to later find it is not economically possible to proceed or that they have failed to secure necessary steps that make completion impossible. At one point, only 8 % of biogas projects in the Netherlands that won bids were actually built.
Brazil had an auction where none of the winning projects were later built.
Projects also under-produce the bidded electricity output (especially in wind and solar projects where projections are more difficult).
“While auctions aim for a specific amount of electricity to be produced or capacity to be installed, empirical experience has shown that a shortfall of the auctioned amount is a rather common phenomenon. This is mainly due to ‘underbidding,’ which results in economically non-feasible projects.” EcoFys, supra, page 45.
“A tender scheme creates competition between bidders and, thus, inherently encourages them to bid as low as possible. However, the evidence in France, Portugal, Nova Scotia, U.K., India, China and Brazil shows that they may overestimate their capacity factors, underestimate their costs (because, for example material costs turn out to be higher than they were expected to be) and follow strategic behavior in bidding (i.e., win the bid, then adjust).” Del Rio, supra, page 51.
“Empirical evidence indicates that low implementation rates caused, e.g. by underbidding or the
existence of non-cost barriers, are one of the main drawbacks of auctions used for RES-support…..it remains to be seen whether auction schemes can eventually achieve the desired effectiveness.” EcoFys, supra, page 72 (emphasis added).
This problem completely undermines the assertion that auctions allow countries to specify the amount of renewable energy they want and to specify a maximum price. The process more typically resembles a “wish-list” than a real “shopping cart.” The period between auctions, given the need to publish in advance the reference prices and other terms, may actually not provide any advantage in adjusting the compensation to fit the investor’s expectations and the public’s limits. Other systems may, in fact, have quicker response times to adjust for the right fit in support levels.
Anti-competitive Impacts
Next, there is abundant evidence that the auction process favors large utilities that have lower cost of capital and a tolerance for lower levels of return on investment. Ironically, this actually lowers long-term competition. The Commission is pushing this process even in Member States where there is already very dominant market control in the electricity market by a few major players (for example, in France- EdF and in Poland- PGE and Tauron and other state-owned firms). These conditions will add to the historical anti-competitive bias of auctions. Distortion in the form of barriers to SMEs is a common result from auction systems:
“[S]maller players have apparently been excluded from auctions in Brazil. Despite the
initial transaction costs for the qualification phase not being excessive, they have excluded smaller
actors. This can partly be attributed to the fact that the required bid bonds have posed significant
barriers for smaller (and for local) potential bidders. And local bidders participating in the auctions
have largely not been able to compete with the underbidding strategies of international investors.” EcoFys, supra, page 52. [they note that big international players seem to be bidding below costs to achieve market position].
Similarly in China, EcoFys noted , supra, page 66 [only large state-owned firms met prequalification terms]. “Only little interest of private investors in state-company dominated market has been observed….these lessons could apply for incumbent players in liberalized markets with high market concentration. Participation of smaller actors should be facilitated.” Id. page 67. But the auction mechanism does not provide the means to do this.
The problem is not limited to the countries where state-owned companies dominate the sector. Large international firms have often exercised similar influence in auctions. While the Commission recognized the problem with small players and small projects, it failed to adjust the guidelines to fit the real world realities:
“Unfriendly for small projects and actors. A major empirical lesson of tenders is that they are unsuitable for small installations and smaller actors.Competition may thus be affected. It has been argued that some of the afore mentioned factors and,namely, information failure and difficult access to finance,have a disproportionately negative impact on small actors and, thus, that the instrument is not suitable for small actors, suggesting that smaller projects should be promoted with a different instrument.” Del Rio, supra, page 52.
The Commission’s approach to this issue to to provide for some discretion to exempt small projects from auctions. Their exclusion from competitive procedures is discretionary and limited to 1 MW for non-wind projects. “Aid may be granted without a competitive bidding process as described in point (127) to installations with an installed electricity capacity of less than 1 MW….” Guidelines, par. 128. There is no indication that there is any factual basis for the 1 MW size ceiling. The presumption made by the Commission should be reversed: small projects less than 5 MW should be presumed to be unsuitable for competitive bidding procedures based on the history of auctions. See infra, p. 5-6.
The most tenacious and intractable problem is that auctions generally only select based on price. This not only results in support going to a couple of lower cost production schemes, but restricts the quality of projects in terms of collateral benefits, such as levels of environmental protection and public health.
Relying solely on the price of electricity ignores the Commission’s own policy of balancing support with environmental benefits. Noise, odor and emissions controls are frequently sacrificed for the need to keep the investor rate of return high enough and still win auctioned support. Long-term advantages of more expensive technologies like biogas used for organic waste management will also not get any priority or consideration in auctions.
Even targeted goals for biogas infrastructure will be outside the scope of a “technology-neutral” auction. Multiple experiences in nations doing auctions support this conclusion:
“The SDE+ is organised in such way that only established, low-cost technologies will receive support. The
Netherlands argue that it will be too expensive to reach the 2020 renewable energy target with innovative projects and technologies. It is however questionable if the target will be reached with only
low-cost technologies.” EcoFys, supra, page 56.
China: “Similar to the auctions for wind, underbidding has been a problem in the Chinese PV auctions. In
addition, realised projects have been characterized by a low quality of power plants.” EcoFys, supra, page 66.
There is little indication that the auction mechanism can be implemented in 28 Member States without them experiencing the same degree of problems that have occurred in the past. The fundamental premises of the Commission’s move to auctions are faulty. There is no flat cost-curve for most of the technologies involved. Setting reference prices and technology bands to assure that a sufficient number of bids occur and that projects are actually built will be quite problematic.
One of the major pro-auction academic reports (Del Rio et al,
supra) observes from a study of dozens of RES auctions:
“Unfortunately, these theoretical advantages of auctions come at a cost. Due to the complexity of the bureaucratic procedures, and also to the planning required ahead, auctions have higher transaction costs which,
together with uncertainties on the final price and the tendering schedule, deter participation by smaller firms, resulting in a low degree of competition and creating opportunities for market power. In turn, this may eliminate the higher theoretical efficiency of this instrument.”
The EcoFys report in 2014, just a couple of months before the Commission approved the new guidelines, completely contradicts the optimism about this device expressed by the Commission. At best, they found auctions to be an experimental tool with some future promise but many limitations and risks. Compelling all future support schemes to use this approach seems irresponsible and unwise.
Missing 2020 Targets
One of the most perplexing things about the new state aid guidelines is why they were pushed into effective just three years before the 2020 deadline. Changes in RES support systems have notoriously influenced the schedule and timing of investment and project development, both positively in the case of high PV FITs and negatively in the case of announcements of downward adjustments. With the majority of Member States
not on track to meet the mandatory 2020 targets for RES,
the rationale for throwing a huge dose of uncertainty into the RES market in Europe seems highly problematic. The move to any new system makes investment more risky and creates financial uncertainty. In the home stretch to 2020, requiring a new system that does not guarantee support for projects that have permits, land agreements, and other approvals in hand can only dampen the enthusiasm of investors. Doing so with the avowed intent of lowering the level of support offered can only have one outcome: fewer projects and more problems meeting mandatory EU targets.
The industry that is expected to invest billions in this sector has identified the problems that have caused so many countries to be lagging in RES development:
“The most important category across all sectors relates to the political and economic framework: it gathers 357 barriers out of 780. This category mainly refers to the existence and reliability of a general RES support scheme, access to finance and the remuneration level of existing support schemes.” Keep on Track 2014, p. 13.
The new guidelines are not helping: “The newly adopted State aid guidelines are limiting the
member states’ freedom of choice of support schemes that have proven to be effective.” Keep on Track 2014, p. 17. “Stop-and-go policies and disruptive changes are currently jeopardising the achievement of the 2020 targets.” Id. “Since the announcement of new state aid guidelines, many potential investors fear less stable conditions. In case the guidelines are implemented as announced, investments will drop to a much lower level.” Id. page 20 (emphasis added).
The negative effect of the new guidelines on RES investment has, in fact, already started in 2014, as
European RES investment has fallen 44%. Bloomberg New Energy Finance,
Global Trends In Renewable Energy Investment (2014) prepared for the United Nations Environmental Program, page 11.
As more Member States juggle their systems to meet the new rules, it is unlikely that this trend will reverse itself.
The negative effect on RES investment from the new state aid package is occurring when most Member States were already off-track to meet their obligatory 2020 targets. It is hard to see the logic of “avoiding over-compensation” when support was already too low to trigger the RES investment necessary in most Member States. This is more puzzling when mechanisms to avoid instances of over-compensation were supposed to be engrained in all of the national support schemes to begin with.
Technology Neutrality
The Commission has moved from requiring levelized RES support that differentiates based on technology to a preference for technology neutrality. This shift is central to the new guidelines and the new GBER exemptions. The premise of technological neutrality is also fundamentally wrong.
The entire basis for technology-neutrality is flawed: the Commission moved from adjustments of support levelized across technologies to these “free-for-all” auctions with no factual basis for their decision. In fact, one of the reports probably originally intended to provide support for changes (EcoFys, January 2014), came out with the opposite conclusion in discussing auctions: “At present we consider the cumulated cost-potential curve in the EU28 to be too steep for technology-neutrality…” Design features of support schemes for renewable electricity, January 2014, p. 23 (emphasis added). The idea started with the Commission’s proposal of state aid to place “deployed technologies” into free-for-all auctions. This “deployed” classification was an attempt to find a surrogate for technologies with comparable cost-curves. See Comments of the Polish Biogas Association, February 2014. As EcoFys noted, “[i]n case of a rather flat cost-resource curve, there might not be a need differentiation, since deployment of the most cost-effective plants is encouraged….” Id. But they did not find the necessary “flat cost-curve” to be present in Europe.
Numerous studies have supported the EcoFys conclusion that the RES technologies found in Member States are not based on comparable cost-curves. The Institute for Renewable Energy in Poland did a 2013 study for the Polish Ministry of Economy for the expressed purpose of determining the differentials in the levelized cost of providing electricity. They found a spread in the necessary support of a factor of more than five across technologies. These included only the technologies called for in the Polish National Action Plan, so Poland was committed to develop each of these technologies under their RES support scheme. IEO, “Analysis on the Possibility Of Determining the Necessary Amount of Support For Individual Res Technologies in the Context of The Implementation of the "National Action Plan For Renewable Energy," (July 2013).
Fraunhofer, LCOE RES (Nov. 2013) [Germany 2012 data]. |
A recent calculation of the levelized cost of production of renewable energy technologies done by the Institute for Solar Energy Systems in Germany (above) also illustrates the vast disparity still remaining between the various technologies. No data from a credible source has been published that suggest all of these technologies faced similar cost-curves. As we noted below, they will need to be grouped by cost in both separate auctions by technology bundles or exempted from auctions by their small size.
Auction advocates ironically use the argument that its mechanism is better than some other systems to adjusting to diverse costs of production by “banding,” having separate auctions by technology or cost of production grouping. See Del Rio, supra. The Commission has also consistently made the same finding in reviewing individual Member State RES plans. See UK decision, July 2014.
Each use of a band by technology undermines the principal assumption of an auction (increased competition), although banding will be inevitably necessary given the disparities in costs of production and national goals in RES technology policies. The results will still be problematic. Banding also does not eliminate the key problem of under-bidding or over pre-qualification. It may, in fact, enhance it since there is a smaller pool of players involved.
What technologies need to be supported? The Commission has ignored the mandates of the RES Directive which required that National Action Plans be approved by the Commission, including the technology mix to be supported. Article 4, Directive 2009/28/EC, requires that “Each Member State shall adopt a national renewable energy action plan. The national renewable energy action plans shall set out Member States’ national targets for the share of energy from renewable sources consumed in transport, electricity and heating and cooling in 2020….” These plans were developed using a mandatory template from the Commission, including specification of the technologies that would be relied upon. Plans had to be approved by the Commission. Inadequate progress toward the 2020 mandatory targets could require the Commission to recommend changes in the plan. Id.
Member States should be compelled to produce support systems that credibly promote the development of the technologies included in their Commission-approved National Plans. It is not a question as most commentators assert of support for “less mature” technologies (the faulty assumption there being that all mature technologies will have comparable costs per MWhr). It is an issue over the inability of the single variable of cost per MWhr of electricity to provide the entirely basis for a policy decision on what should be built. Biogas with a higher cost per MWhr (see Fraunhofer on previous page) may be required for organic waste management plans or regulations (like the Animal Byproducts Regulation). It offers benefits that greater exceed the production of green electricity. But biogas costs of production are not going down as PV and wind technologies are doing. The issue is not support of “less mature” technologies (assuming that this is a surrogate for cost of production), but the issue is simply the relative cost of production. The existing state aid rules get it right and the new guidelines get lost in a somewhat naïve infatuation with competitive procedures (which have normally ended up being anti-competitive in practice).
The Commission’s approval of the UK auction plan involving “contracts for the difference” still involved separate auctions in three groups based on levelized cost of production as well as an exclusion of all projects under 5 MW. See State aid SA.36196 (2014/N) – United Kingdom Electricity Market Reform - Contract for Difference for Renewable, July 23, 2014. The Commission did not consider the UK National Action Plan in this decision, which would require sufficient support for each technology included to satisfy both the DG Competition’s state aid rules and the DG Energy’s RES Directive.
The technology neutral auction has proven to be problematic in terms of its results as well:
“Thus, technology-neutral auction design tends to provide only very limited development possibilities for less mature technologies (low dynamic efficiency) and can limit the variety of market participants, since smaller actors may not be able or willing to bear the transaction costs of participating in an auction” EcoFys, supra, page 73.
“If a technology-neutral design is selected, implementing additional measures to stimulate less mature technologies and smaller-scale technologies should be considered.” EcoFys, supra¸page 73.
The technology-neutral auction has the greatest chance of being anti-competitive and unfair to smaller players, yet the Commission new policy makes this the “default setting:”
The bidding process can be limited to specific technologies where a process open to all generators would lead to a suboptimal result which cannot be addressed in the process design in view of in particular:
(i) the longer-term potential of a given new and innovative technology; or
(ii) the need to achieve diversification; or
(iii) network constraints and grid stability; or
(iv) system (integration) costs; or
(v) the need to avoid distortions on the raw material markets from biomass support Member States shall carry out a detailed assessment of the applicability of such conditions and report it to the Commission according to the modalities described in Article 11 (a).
Art. 42(3), Commission Regulation (EU) No 651/2014, June 17, 2014.
There is no clear basis for shifting from levelized support policies to uniform support policies when the underlying technologies still have more than a five-fold difference in cost of production. Member States can elect to use two or three of the cheapest technologies in their National Action Plan under the RES Directive (as Sweden has) but it is generally not possible for Member States to meet 2020 targets without a more diverse mix of technology. Most Member States are already set up for failure in 2020 and inadequate support for diverse technologies (even those in their National Action Plans) is the leading reason.
The guidelines still allow Member States to make determinations to avoid auctions altogether under certain circumstances described in par. 127:
Aid is granted in a competitive bidding process on the basis of clear, transparent and non-discriminatory criteria, unless:
(i) Member States demonstrate that only one or a very limited number of projects or sites could be eligible; or
(ii) Member States demonstrate that a competitive bidding process would lead to higher support levels (for example to avoid strategic bidding); or
(iii) Member States demonstrate that a competitive bidding process would result in low project realisation rates (avoid underbidding).”
The fact is that virtually all of the above exceptions in the Commission’s text are the rule for auctions done to date. They are not sporadic artifacts of poorly conceived auctions, but the dominant characteristics of auctions done to date. Low project realization rates are a nearly universal problem. It has been corrected most frequently by imposing pre-qualification requirements that result in a very low number of bidders, generally rewarding market concentration. EcoFys conclusion in the Commission-funded report earlier in 2014 is striking: “it remains to be seen whether auction schemes can eventually achieve the desired effectiveness (emphasis added).”
Member States’ burden to demonstrate a problem with underbidding to avoid auction procedures is also a tautology. Competitive bidding procedures have normally resulted in “low project realization rates.” How will a Member State prove that a prospective auction will have this problem, other than to draw on the past experiences elsewhere? Competitive bidding with restrictive pre-qualifications (to address underbidding) leads to higher bids due to increased risks for the bidder. This normally results in bid prices that could have been readily achieved with a fixed instrument (no savings) or in no bids at all (no savings and no projects). The Commission does nothing to resolve the historical problems of auctions, while making them the presumptive norm.
Exemption from Notification
But those electing to avoid auction problems will have to notify and await Commission approval. The exemption from notification requires:
“ Aid shall be granted in a competitive bidding process on the basis of clear, transparent and non-discriminatory criteria which shall be open to all generators producing electricity from renewable energy sources on a non-discriminatory basis.” Art. 42(2), Commission Regulation (EU) No 651/2014, June 17, 2014.
Members States wishing to invoke the exceptions in the state aid guidelines from Section 127 will be compelled to submit a notification package and await approval. So the GBER exemption is being used as a bludgeon to pound Member State’s into auction procedures.
While the basis for a notification exemption for auctions is fundamentally wrong, the applicability of the exemption will undoubtedly prove to be problematic. How small projects are handled, what bands are used by technology, how reference prices are set, what technologies are exempted, and other procedures will all raise issues that normally would be part of the DG Competition’s review of the state aid involved. It is dubious that simply announcing that auctions that are transparent and open to all bidders will satisfy all of the competition and fairness concerns. Complaints can be expected that will have the effect of getting the Commission into these issues even where a Member State tries to claim a block grant exemption.
Certificates
The Guidelines also allow certificate systems to continue, although they have more restrictions than in the past. Section 3.3.1.4. (“Aid granted by way of certificates”) provides the guidance.
(136) Member States may grant support for renewable energy sources by using market mechanisms such as green certificates. These market mechanisms allow all renewable energy producers to benefit indirectly from guaranteed demand for their energy, at a price above the market price for conventional power. The price of these green certificates is not fixed in advance, but depends on market supply and demand.
Certificate systems have enjoyed Commission support in the past precisely because their market value floats with supply and demand. This is also a huge potential draw back if the scheme is not done in a way to limit distortion of the market. Generally, the distortion has occurred because some technologies have a significant price edge and end up with a lion’s share of certificates, which especially if accumulated year-to-year, can cause an over-supply that destroys the certificate value.
Left: Polish Economic Chamber for Renewable Energy graphic, from Detailed Paper on Green Certificates.
Poland is a classic case of this effect: The practice of co-firing biomass with coal and old hydro plants received the same support (one certificate per MWhr) as other technologies, leading to the collapse of the market, especially since certificates have been allowed to accumulate. Over 70% of the certificates are going to these suppliers (mostly state-owned companies).
The Polish Ministry of Economy explained: “Multi-fuel co-firing plants contributed the most to the rapid increase in the volume of electricity production from renewable energy sources which in recent years recorded the highest growth (which is related to low expenditure necessary to run this type of production and high revenues generated by this practice). As recently as July 2, 2014,
the Polish Government still criticized the uniform support system noting that “
technology showing the lowest cost of power generation received unjustified support.” Regulatory Impact Analysis, July 23014 bill, p. 21.
The current Polish system is the subject of a Commission investigation,
SA.37224 (2013/CP) — Polish system of green certificates for co-firing coal plants.
Despite the huge problems caused in Poland by the single certificate value as late as 2014, the Commission is now pushing the idea of a single value in the hopes of creating competition. “The Commission considers in particular that no differentiation in support levels through green certificates may be applied unless a Member States demonstrates the need for a differentiation….” Guidelines, par. 138. This is, of course, a complete reversal of the rules in the 2008 guidelines that required differentiation to levelize support across technologies. Community Guidelines on State Aid For Environmental Protection, section 109 (2008/C 82/01). See C(2010)2211, State aid No N 65/2010 - United Kingdom Amendments to the Renewables Obligation Certificates (ROCs) scheme, March 30, 2010 (“…levelised costs matching the midpoint of the predicted revenues… will therefore prevent overcompensation in the aggregate of the different producers”); C(2005)480, State aid No N 362/2004 – United Kingdom Renewables Obligation Order 2005, November 23, 2005; C (2011) 4938, State aid SA. 33134 2011/N– RO, Green certificates for promoting electricity from renewable sources, July 13, 201
At this point, the Commission will only allow differentiation of certificate values (levelization) after 2017, based on the same criteria for technology banding of auctions:
“(i) the longer-term potential of a given new and innovative technology; or
(ii) the need to achieve diversification; or
(iii) network constraints and grid stability; or
(iv) system (integration) costs; or
(v) the need to avoid distortions on the raw material markets from biomass support.”
Guidelines, supra, par. 137.
The need to achieve diversification can presumably be justified by the technology mix contained in the National Renewable Energy Action Plan for the RES Directive. So the bar may not be set very high here for a program to institute or maintain differentiated certificates. However, it remains mysterious as to what changed in the market over a relatively few number of years that requires the Commission to turn its presumption on the need to levelize on its head. Changes in the cost of RES in some technologies, such as wind and in the future PV, clearly show that the need for huge support levels is diminishing. But the fixed value systems (FITs and FIPs) can also reflect that development as can adjusted certificate coefficients. While the absolute cost per MWhr of some technologies is falling, the differential between technologies including some that will be necessary to meet National Action Plans for 2020 have not shrunk. They may be, in fact, growing as wind and PV prices come down.
The failure to levelize can still cause all of the adverse effects on competition that the Commission has strived to eliminate in the past. Nothing on the ground has changed fundamentally to alter this fact. Yet the Commission is erecting barriers to Member States doing what was viewed as legally obligatory until the new rules. There is no GBER exemption for certificate programs, even single value certificates. See Article 42, Commission Regulation (EU) No 651/2014, June 17, 2014. In reality, the policies involving certificates have been sorted out in several Commission decisions and are relatively straight-forward compared to the procedures that should be used in auctions and their potential problems. The fact that auctions which would superficially meet all of the GBER exemption tests have nevertheless resulted in market concentration would seem to undermine the whole new structure.
Balancing
There is a big emphasis in the new guidelines on balancing obligations.
The Guidelines, as EuroElectric urged, seek to impose
“´standard balancing responsibilities´ mean non-discriminatory balancing responsibilities across technologies which do not exempt any generator from those responsibilities.” Section 1.3(38). The Guidelines provide that “Beneficiaries [of RES support] are subject to standard balancing responsibilities, unless no liquid intra-day markets exist.”
Infra, par. 125(b). The balancing issue will be one of the major controversies over the next decade. However, the auction
mechanism is not particularly well-suited to impose balancing obligations. Moreover, other provisions of the guidelines actually impede balancing.
“
One usually cited disadvantage of auctions is that they do not give the right market signals to RE producers, which are therefore not encouraged to produce in peak times, to focus maintenance on lower demand seasons, or, generally, to increase operational efficiency. Del Rio,
supra.
They propose using feed-in premiums to correct this flaw. Their solution of contracts for the difference may work to encourage meeting demand curves,
but there is no inherent requirement that the support awarded in an auction differentiate between peak and non-peak hours, just as there is no requirement in most FIT systems.
The solution funneled through grid sales will likely be more complex, less flexible and more unfriendly to smaller players than simply allowing direct sales of electricity to end-users. Distributed energy offers a solution that is far more direct, manageable and flexible.
It is noteworthy, that while the European Union has championed “distributed energy” for years, that the Guidelines do not use the term anywhere in their text.
If critics wonder about the influence of the large conventional utilities on the DG Competition, they need look no further than this fact.
Certificate systems can now allow for direct sales to occur
and these schemes can continue under the new guidelines, but only if they go through elaborate efforts at notification. The Guidelines would require that certificate programs meet the Section 125 requirements that include sale of electricity on the market.
Infra, Section 138 (“where technically possible”).
The major savings for renewable energy in the lower run is its ability to provide “distributed energy” in the local communities where the energy is used. By moving closer to the energy user, this type of RES can reduce distribution charges that account for about half of the end-user’s bill. Distributed energy is supported by Commission in theory and then undermined by Commission in the state aid guidelines by apparently forcing sale to grid.
By eliminating direct sales to end users except for very small installations, the guidelines restrict distributed energy by definition. Direct sales can achieve consumer savings and higher margins for RES producers
without additional government support. Local use of energy lowers distribution prices. If the objective of the state aid package was to reduce the adverse impact on RES support on end-user prices, then the Commission could not have made a more irrational decision.
The discrimination against small facilities from auctions
will hurt distributed energy, but the requirement to connect to the grid cuts off a major market mechanism that could provide for more cost-effective support.
A major way that renewable energy can promote energy security is through dispersed generation into local grids or direct to users. Biogas has one of the highest potentials for this application, since it can take organic wastes from food and meat processing and directly sell the energy back to the waste producer. This is also a vital way to create incentives for more sound waste management practices. Smaller sources can find electricity markets in the local area with transmission costs much lower than the grid. This can also be much more profitable than sales to the grid for the RES facility. Biogas can be stored over-night and generation increased in the day during peak hours. So in the right support scheme, biogas can not only balance itself, but improver the net grid balance. This also provides improved revenue for market sales during peak hours. This creates better incentives to invest in such projects without raising the support levels or impacting consumer prices negatively. Obstructing such developments is a major distortion of the market to favor the big utilities and to do so in a way that offers no advantages to consumers.
Section 125 may make community-based biogas impossible when combined with the 1 MW ceiling on exception from auctions. It is pretty obvious that the only reason for these restrictions is to limit competition not to protect it. Differential certificates, so essential for biogas and other technologies that do not have the lowest cost per MWhr also must undergo a full notification and approval process with a presumption against the need to levelize (exactly the opposite of the 2008 guidelines, which have been changed even though the relative cost of production has not changed).
Conclusion
The European Commission is given the task of assuring fair competition within the community. One important part of that is to provide assurances that state aid has the smallest impact on competition necessary to achieve the common goals of European legislation. For many years the Commission fought to levelize support across technologies, avoid discrimination against new RES technologies, and encourage small and medium enterprises to enter the energy market.
Yet in the new state aid guidelines and GBER regulation, the Commission departs from consistent positions taken in the past. The mechanism for awarding support would be the procedure most favorable to large utilities, the scheme most likely to discourage small projects and small developers. The support for various technologies would be flattened, not levelized, dropping to the lowest denominator. Distributed energy would be limited to sources of 500 kW assuring no serious market threat to the major utilities. The pace of RES investment has slowed considerably. All of these twists and turns have only one thing in common, that they favor the large established utilities.
The guidelines are only guidelines and in the end they can be challenged case-by-case as new Member State schemes come into play. Despite the depressing thought of delayed justice, it may also be that the European Court is destined to sort out the issues.
“
“None of the three countries investigated currently have a model that is likely to help Germany reach the three goals of its Energiewende: affordability, targets for renewables, and competition between large corporations and SMEs.” The Energie Wende Blog, June 25, 2014 (citing IZES study 2014].
“In order to incentivise the market integration of electricity from renewable sources, it is important that beneficiaries sell their electricity directly in the market and are subject to market obligations. The following conditions apply from 1 January 2016 to all new aid schemes and measures: (a) Aid is granted as a premium in addition to the market price (premium)whereby the generators sell its electricity directly in the market.
(b) Beneficiaries66 are subject to standard balancing responsibilities, unless no liquid intra-day markets exist.
(c) Measures are put in place to ensure that generators have no incentive to generate electricity under negative prices.” Guidelines, supra, par. 125.
Even in normal auctions in Brazil, “a large share of the selected projects are heavily delayed, thereby negatively affecting the effectiveness of the auctions” EcoFys, supra, page 53. In the Netherlands: “The realisation rate of projects so far amounts to roughly 40% of the projects that were committed in 2011…” EcoFys, supra¸page 57. This is apparently a contradiction from the Commission’s intent to promote innovation and to not allow aid to some firms to restrict RES development.
“That might lead to a situation where, due to the aid granted to some firms, more efficient or innovative competitors, for example competitors with a different, possibly even cleaner technology, that would otherwise be able to enter and expand are unable to do so. In the long run, interfering with the competitive entry and exit process may stifle innovation and slow down industry-wide productivity This was summarized by the head of the Polish Office of Competition in a June 5, 2012 letter to the Ministry of Economy: the Commission notes whether it is necessary to ensure the viability of energy production, does not provide overcompensation for the production costs' of energy (proportional size of the planned instruments is relation to actual costs) and does not dissuade producers of energy from increasing competitiveness. In order to demonstrate this, it is necessary to provide the Commission with a detailed justification of the necessity and proportionality of the envisaged measures. In particular, it is necessary to analyze the markets in which the beneficiaries operate for the planned measures, the real costs of energy production incurred by them depending on the type of RES and CHP technology in relation to the achievable rates the sale of the energy and the rate of return on investment for different types of RES and CHP technologies” OCCP to Min. of Economy, June 5, 2012. Del Rio, page 52: “Larger installations facilitate economies of scale in production but a model of distributed generation calls for smaller plants scattered around the territory.” Of special interest to biogas and other technologies is the fact that the guidelines exempt 1 MW projects from the auction, but exclude up to 6 MW for wind projects. There is absolutely no justification for this distinction and is distorts competition in violation of the Treaty.
Comments